Shifts in Supply and Demand for Bonds (2024)

Learning Objective

  1. What causes the supply and demand for bonds to shift?

Shifting supply and demand curves around can be fun, but figuring out why the curves shift is the interesting part. (Determining the shape and slope of the curves is interesting too, but these details will not detain us here.) Movements along the curve, or why the supply curve slopes upward and the demand curve downward, were easy enough to grasp. Determining why the whole curve moves, why investors are willing to buy more (or fewer) bonds, or why borrowers are willing to sell more (or fewer) bonds at a given price is a bit more involved. Let’s tackle demand first, then we will move on to supply.

Wealth determines the overall demand for assets. An asset (something owned) is any store of value, including financial assets like money, loans (for the lender), bonds, equities (stocks), and a potpourri of derivativeswww.margrabe.com/Dictionary/DictionaryAC.html#sectA and nonfinancial assets like real estate (land, buildings), precious metals (gold, silver, platinum), gems (diamonds, rubies, emeralds), hydrocarbons (oil, natural gas) and (to a greater or lesser extent, depending on their qualities) all other physical goods (as opposed to bads, like pollution, or freebies, like air). As wealth increases, so too does the quantity demanded of all types of assets, though to different degrees. The reasoning here is almost circular: if it is to be maintained, wealth must be invested in some asset, in some store of value. In which type of asset to invest new wealth is the difficult decision. When determining which assets to hold, most economic entities (people, firms, governments) care about many factors, but for most investors most of the time, three variables—expected relative return, risk, and liquidity—are paramount.

Expected relative return is the ex ante (before the fact) belief that the return on one asset will be higher than the returns of other comparable (in terms of risk and liquidity) assets. Return is a good thing, of course, so as expected relative return increases, the demand for an asset also increases (the entire demand curve shifts right). That can happen because the expected return on the asset itself increases, because the expected return on comparables decreases, or because of a combination thereof. Clearly, two major factors will affect return expectations and hence the demand for certain financial assets, like bonds: expected interest rates and, via the Fisher Equation, expected inflation. If the interest rate is expected to increase for any reason (including, but not limited to, expected increases in inflation), bond prices are expected to fall, so the demand will decrease (the entire demand curve will shift left). Conversely, if the interest rate is thought to decrease for any reason (including, but not limited to, the expected taming of inflation), bond prices are expected to rise, so the entire demand curve will shift right.

Overall, though, calculating relative expected returns is sticky business that is best addressed in more specialized financial books and courses. If you want an introduction, investigate the capital asset pricing model (CAPM)www.valuebasedmanagement.net/methods_capm.html;www.moneychimp.com/articles/valuation/capm.htm and the arbitrage pricing theory (APT).moneyterms.co.uk/apt Calculating return is not terribly difficult and neither is comparing returns among a variety of assets. What’s tricky is forecasting future returns and making sure that assets are comparable by controlling for risk, among other things. Risk is the uncertainty of an asset’s returns. It comes in a variety of flavors, all of them unsavory, so as it increases, the demand decreases (the entire curve shifts left), ceteris paribus. Two major types of risk are default risk (aka credit risk), the chance that a financial contract will not be honored, and interest rate risk, the chance that the interest rate will rise and hence decrease a bond or loan’s price. An offsetting risk is called reinvestment risk, which bites when the interest rate decreases because coupon or other interest payments have to be reinvested at a lower yield to maturity. To be willing to take on more risk, whatever its flavor, rational investors must expect a higher relative return. Investors who require a much higher return for assuming a little bit of risk are called risk-averse. Those who will take on much risk for a little higher return are called risk-loving, risk-seekers, or risk-tolerant. (Investors who take on more risk without compensation are neither risk-averse nor risk-tolerant, but rather irrational.) Risks can be idiosyncratic (pertinent to a particular company), sectoral (pertinent to an entire industry, like trucking or restaurants), or systemic (economy-wide). Liquidity risk occurs when an asset cannot be sold as quickly or cheaply as expected, be it for idiosyncratic, sectoral, or systemic reasons. This, too, is a serious risk because liquidity, or (to be more precise) liquidity relative to other assets, is the third major determinant of asset demand. Because investors often need to change their investment portfolioThe set of financial and other investments or assets held by an economic entity. or dis-save (spend some of their wealth on consumption), liquidity, the ability to sell an asset quickly and cheaply, is a good thing. The more liquid an asset is, therefore, the further right the demand curve for it will shift, all else being equal.

During the financial crisis that began in 2007, the prices of a certain type of bond collateralized by subprime mortgages, long-term loans collateralized with homes and made to relatively risky borrowers, collapsed. In other words, their yields had to increase markedly to induce investors to own them. They dropped in price after investors realized that the bonds, a type of asset-backed security (ABS), had much higher default rates and much lower levels of liquidity than they had previously believed. Figure 5.6 "Variables that influence demand for bonds" summarizes the chapter discussion so far.

So much for demand. Why does the supply curve for bonds shift to and fro? There are many reasons, but the three main ones are government budgets, inflation expectations, and general business conditions. When governments run budget deficits, they often borrow by selling bonds, pushing the supply curve rightward and bond prices down (yields up), ceteris paribus. When governments run surpluses, and they occasionally do, believe it or not, they redeem and/or buy their bonds back on net, pushing the supply curve to the left and bond prices up (yields down), all else being equal. (For historical time series data on the U.S. national debt, which was usually composed mostly of bonds, browse http://www.economagic.com/em-cgi/data.exe/treas/pubdebt.)

Stop and Think Box

You are a copyeditor for Barron’s. What, if anything, appears wrong in the following sentence? How do you know?

“Recent increases in the profitability of investments, inflation expectations, and government surpluses will surely lead to increased bond supplies in the near future.”

Government deficits, not surpluses, lead to increased bond supplies.

The expectation of higher inflation, other factors held constant, will cause borrowers to issue more bonds, driving the supply curve rightward, and bond prices down (and yields up). The Fisher Equation, ir = i – πe, explains this nicely. If the inflation expectation term πe increases while nominal interest rate i stays the same, the real interest rate ir must decrease. From the perspective of borrowers, the real cost of borrowing falls, which means that borrowing becomes more attractive. So they sell bonds.

Borrowing also becomes more attractive when general business conditions become more favorable, as when taxes and regulatory costs decrease or the economy expands. Although individuals sometimes try to borrow out of financial weakness or desperation, relatively few such loans are made because they are high risk. Most economic entities borrow out of strength, to finance expansion and engage in new projects they believe will be profitable. So when economic prospects are good, taxes are low, and regulations are not too costly, businesses are eager to borrow, often by selling bonds, shifting the supply curve to the right and bond prices down (yields up). Figure 5.7 "Variables that determine the supply of bonds" summarizes the chapter discussion so far.

Figure 5.7 Variables that determine the supply of bonds

Shifts in Supply and Demand for Bonds (2)

As Yoda might say, “Pause here, we must” to make sure we’re on track.www.yodaspeak.co.uk/index.php Try out these questions until you are comfortable. Remember that the ceteris paribus condition holds in each.

Exercises

  1. What will happen to bond prices if stock trading commissions decrease? Why?
  2. What will happen to bond prices if bond trading commissions increase? Why?
  3. What will happen to bond prices if the government implements tax increases? Why?
  4. If government revenues drop significantly (and remember all else stays the same, including government expenditures), what will likely happen to bond prices? Why?
  5. If the government guaranteed the payment of bonds, what would happen to their prices? Why?
  6. What will happen to bond prices if the government implements regulatory reforms that reduce regulatory costs for businesses? Why?
  7. If government revenues increase significantly, what will likely happen to bond prices? Why?
  8. What will happen to bond prices if terrorism ended and the world’s nations unilaterally disarmed and adopted free trade policies? Why?
  9. What will happen to bond prices if world peace brought substantially lower government budget deficits?

If you’ve already figured out that expected inflation will decrease bond prices, and increase bond yields, by both shifting the supply curve to the right and the demand curve to the left, as in Figure 5.8 "Expected inflation and bond prices" , kudos to you!

Figure 5.8 Expected inflation and bond prices

Shifts in Supply and Demand for Bonds (3)

If you noticed that the response of bond prices and yields to a business cycle expansion is indeterminate, booya! As noted above, a boom shifts the bond supply curve to the right by inducing businesses to borrow and thus take advantage of the bonanza. Holding demand constant, that action reduces bond prices (raises the interest rate). But demand does not stay constant because economic expansion increases wealth, which increases demand for bonds (shifts the curve to the right), which in turn increases bond prices (reduces the interest rate). The net effect on the interest rate, therefore, depends on how much each curve shifts, as in Figure 5.9 "Business cycle expansion and bond prices".

Figure 5.9 Business cycle expansion and bond prices

Shifts in Supply and Demand for Bonds (4)

In reality, the first scenario is the one that usually wins out: during expansions, the interest rate usually rises, and during recessions, it always falls. For example, the interest rate fell to very low levels during the Great Depression (an almost worldwide downturn in economic output in the early 1930s) and during Japan’s extended economic funk (period of low to no increase in per capita incomes) in the 1990s.www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=10000101&refer=japan&sid=a28sELjm9W04

Key Takeaways

  • The demand curve for bonds shifts due to changes in wealth, expected relative returns, risk, and liquidity.
  • Wealth, returns, and liquidity are positively related to demand; risk is inversely related to demand.
  • Wealth sets the general level of demand. Investors then trade off risk for returns and liquidity.
  • The supply curve for bonds shifts due to changes in government budgets, inflation expectations, and general business conditions.
  • Deficits cause governments to issue bonds and hence shift the bond supply curve right; surpluses have the opposite effect.
  • Expected inflation leads businesses to issue bonds because inflation reduces real borrowing costs, ceteris paribus; decreases in expected inflation or deflation expectations have the opposite effect.
  • Expectations of future general business conditions, including tax reductions, regulatory cost reduction, and increased economic growth (economic expansion or boom), induce businesses to borrow (issue bonds), while higher taxes, more costly regulations, and recessions shift the bond supply curve left.
  • Theoretically, whether a business expansion leads to higher interest rates or not depends on the degree of the shift in the bond supply and demand curves.
  • An expansion will cause the bond supply curve to shift right, which alone will decrease bond prices (increase the interest rate).
  • But expansions also cause the demand for bonds to increase (the bond demand curve to shift right), which has the effect of increasing bond prices (and hence lowering bond yields).
  • Empirically, the bond supply curve typically shifts much further than the bond demand curve, so the interest rate usually rises during expansions and always falls during recessions.
Shifts in Supply and Demand for Bonds (2024)

FAQs

Shifts in Supply and Demand for Bonds? ›

An expansion will cause the bond supply curve to shift right, which alone will decrease bond prices (increase the interest rate). But expansions also cause the demand for bonds to increase (the bond demand curve to shift right), which has the effect of increasing bond prices (and hence lowering bond yields).

How does supply and demand affect bonds? ›

Supply and demand determine bond prices (and bond yields). The bond supply curve is the relationship between the price and the quantity of bonds people are willing to sell, all else equal. The higher the price of a bond, the larger the quantity supplied.

What shifts the supply of bonds? ›

The supply curve for bonds shifts due to changes in government budgets, inflation expectations, and general business conditions. Deficits cause governments to issue bonds and hence shift the bond supply curve right; surpluses have the opposite effect.

What changes a movement along the bond demand or supply curve? ›

Answer and Explanation: The movement along the bond demand curve or supply curve is caused by the bond price. As the bond prices increase then the demand for bond will decrease and the supply for bond will increase, and vice-versa.

What is the supply and demand for bonds framework? ›

Answer and Explanation:

With an expectation of inflation's rise, the supply of bonds and the interest rates will increase, whereas the price of bonds and their demand will fall. When inflation is expected to decline, the supply of bonds and interest rates will decrease, and bonds' prices and demand will rise.

What happens to supply and demand when the Fed buys bonds? ›

If the central bank wants interest rates to be lower, it buys bonds. Buying bonds injects money into the money market, increasing the money supply. When the central bank wants interest rates to be higher, it sells off bonds, pulling money out of the money market and decreasing the money supply.

Which of the following affects both the supply and demand for bonds? ›

Thus, inflation affects both the supply and demand of bonds.

What does an increase in the supply of bonds lead to? ›

An expansion will cause the bond supply curve to shift right, which alone will decrease bond prices (increase the interest rate). But expansions also cause the demand for bonds to increase (the bond demand curve to shift right), which has the effect of increasing bond prices (and hence lowering bond yields).

What causes bonds to go up? ›

Essentially, the price of a bond goes up and down depending on the value of the income provided by its coupon payments relative to broader interest rates. If prevailing interest rates increase above the bond's coupon rate, the bond becomes less attractive.

What shifts money supply and demand? ›

Remember that the shifters of money demand include a change in the price level, a change in real GDP output, and a change in the transaction costs of spending money. The only shifter of the supply of money is the Federal Reserve.

What are movements and shifts in demand and supply curves? ›

Here's one way to remember: a movement along a demand curve, resulting in a change in quantity demanded, is always caused by a shift in the supply curve. Similarly, a movement along a supply curve, resulting in a change in quantity supplied, is always caused by a shift in the demand curve.

What does usually bond supply curve shift to in recession? ›

TRUE: In a recession, when there are fewer expected profitable investment opportunities, the supply of bonds falls, i.e., the supply curve shifts to the left. Conversely, in a business cycle expansion, the supply of bonds will increase with the increased amount of good investment opportunities.

What is the interaction of demand and supply? ›

The law of supply and demand combines two fundamental economic principles describing how changes in the price of a resource, commodity, or product affect its supply and demand. As the price increases, supply rises while demand declines. Conversely, as the price drops supply constricts while demand grows.

Are bonds affected by supply and demand? ›

As with any free-market economy, bond prices are affected by supply and demand. Bonds are issued initially at par value, or $100.

How does money supply affect demand for bonds? ›

If there is an increase in the money supply, bond prices will increase. When the money supply increases, nominal interest rates decrease. Bond prices and interest rates are inversely related, so when interest rates go down, bond prices go up.

What happens to the demand for bonds in a recession? ›

Potential for Increased Value. As investors seek safer assets during a recession, the demand for bonds typically increases. This increased demand can drive up the price of existing bonds, especially those with higher interest rates compared to new bonds being issued.

What happens to bond prices when money supply increases? ›

This is a correct option because when the money supply in the economy increase, the value of money all falls which tends to lower the interest rates. As there is inverse relationship between price of bonds and interest rates so with the fall in interest rate, bond prices increases.

What happens to bonds when money demand increases? ›

An increase in money demand due to a change in expectations, preferences, or transactions costs that make people want to hold more money at each interest rate will have the opposite effect. The money demand curve will shift to the right and the demand for bonds will shift to the left.

How does supply and demand affect interest rates? ›

Interest rate levels are a factor in the supply and demand of credit: an increase in the demand for money or credit will raise interest rates, while a decrease in the demand for credit will decrease them.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Kieth Sipes

Last Updated:

Views: 5995

Rating: 4.7 / 5 (47 voted)

Reviews: 94% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Kieth Sipes

Birthday: 2001-04-14

Address: Suite 492 62479 Champlin Loop, South Catrice, MS 57271

Phone: +9663362133320

Job: District Sales Analyst

Hobby: Digital arts, Dance, Ghost hunting, Worldbuilding, Kayaking, Table tennis, 3D printing

Introduction: My name is Kieth Sipes, I am a zany, rich, courageous, powerful, faithful, jolly, excited person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.